Will the Reserve Bank of Australia (RBA) raise rates today? The market is not quite as sure as a week ago. A two-thirds chance of a small hike is priced in. That small hike would take rates from 0.1% up to 0.25%. The market was pricing in a 100% chance of a small hike last week after the earth-shattering inflation figure. But confidence in the RBA’s response has cooled. Why?
The RBA is supposed to be an inflation-fighting central bank. Inflation is certainly fighting back. It clocked in at 5.1% annual in the most recent official data, the highest result in decades.
Still, a rate rise this afternoon is not certain. There are signs the central bank might choose not to act:
- The most recent official pronouncement from the RBA governor suggested he would wait to look at data on inflation and wages “over coming months” before lifting rates. There has been no update to that statement, and not all the “data” referred to — i.e. the wage price index — has yet come out. The bank could have, if it chose to, updated us. It could schedule a speech, host a webinar, or get its message out through the media. But no deputy governors have been spotted at a podium. Nor does scanning the press for signs of a background briefing of a top economics scribe reveal anything. Nobody seems to have the good oil on a rate rise. Which suggests the most recent pronouncements are meant to stand.
- An election campaign is going on. At the end of that, the RBA is up for review. The RBA is independent in its actions but ultimately this is a democracy and we the people control it through our representatives. The RBA should be worried about upsetting us — but might it also be worried about upsetting our representatives?
The RBA wants to preserve its credibility in two ways: to be taken seriously as an enemy of high inflation, but also by its statements acting as a reliable guide to its actions. At the moment it faces a challenging choice between those two kinds of credibility.
Cue the critics
If the RBA leaves interest rates on hold there will be furore. People will say it moves too slowly. They have a point. Inflation data is backward-looking, so the 5.1% inflation figure recently released applies to January, February and March this year. A May rate rise would flow through to mortgages over weeks and work its way through the economy over the next six months. You could argue any rate rise is nine months too long in gestation.
The argument that the bank has already waited too long makes sense. However, the argument that waiting another month to act won’t change much is also somewhat credible. Monetary policy is not a direct lever with which the RBA controls consumer price inflation. Rate hikes works in five main ways:
- By crimping our spending power (via diverting more of our earnings to paying off loans)
- By encouraging people to save, not spend
- By reducing the amount people and companies can borrow to spend
- By lifting our exchange rate, making imports cheaper and domestic goods more expensive
- By reducing asset prices and making their owners feel poorer
In summary, it works by making us spend less on local goods, thereby reducing their prices. This is certainly not a costless approach. The RBA is right to be cautious. Many are the central banks that have made their people poorer by raising interest rates too hard and precipitating a recession.
But also much of our inflation is imported. What good is it depressing the local economy to try to dig out inflation when its roots are in Ukraine, in the Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC), in the commodities trading desks of Chicago? We live in an increasingly global world with a global coffee price, oil price, beef price, etc.
In the past few decades, the pattern of Australian inflation has been domestic goods getting more expensive while imports grow in price very slowly. For example, T-shirts made in Bangladesh cost $14 now, while haircuts in Melbourne cost, well, hundreds if you’re a woman going to a fancy place. This means Australians earn higher wages but can buy lots of goods cheaply.
But more recently, something has changed. Inflation in tradeable items is suddenly very high, as the next chart shows.
Can we affect their price with tight monetary policy? The labour on those goods is all done offshore and the price of importing them is set on global markets. You might crush the price of a haircut with tight monetary policy, but good luck affecting the price of imported commodities. All you can affect is the margin importers can charge.
If the RBA chooses not to act today, the new composition of inflation is likely to be one reason why.
Crikey is committed to hosting lively discussions. Help us keep the conversation useful, interesting and welcoming. We aim to publish comments quickly in the interest of promoting robust conversation, but we’re a small team and we deploy filters to protect against legal risk. Occasionally your comment may be held up while we review, but we’re working as fast as we can to keep the conversation rolling.
The Crikey comment section is members-only content. Please subscribe to leave a comment.
The Crikey comment section is members-only content. Please login to leave a comment.